Doug Elmendorf ’83, testifying before the Senate Budget Committee in January.

Deficit disorder

Alumni experts weigh in on the nation’s budget gap

Mark Bernstein headhsot
By Mark F. Bernstein ’83
11 min read

The lawmakers who enact the federal budget work in marbled splendor on Capitol Hill. But just a few blocks away the Congressional Budget Office, which analyzes those budget figures and ensures their integrity, is tucked away on a middle floor of the utterly nondescript Ford House Office Building.  

There, where D Street leads into the on-ramp for I-395, the décor is fluorescent lighting, dropped ceilings, and linoleum tile, which is a bit underwhelming considering that the CBO is one of the most useful arms of the legislative branch. On a chilly Wednesday in early January, just a few hours after the 112th Congress took office, CBO director Doug Elmendorf ’83 issues an analysis of the country’s fiscal future that is as spartan as the government-issued table he sits behind. A tall, lean man with glasses and a closely trimmed beard, Elmendorf looks very much like the policy wonk he is. His job is to be analytical and nonpartisan, so he chooses his words carefully.

“Predicting the deficit is very difficult, because you are trying to predict the difference between two very large numbers,” he says, referring to government revenues and outlays. “But I think there is no doubt that the underlying structural factors affecting the budget deficit are adverse under current policy.”

Translation: We are deep in red ink and getting deeper. 

Joshua Bolten ’76 at a gathering sponsored by The Economist magazine in October.

Bloomberg via Getty Images — Ramin Talaie

 Joshua Bolten ’76 at a gathering sponsored by The Economist magazine in October.

Several weeks later, another Princetonian, Joshua Bolten ’76, gave much the same assessment — this time, in an underground classroom in Robertson Hall. Bolten, who served as director of the Office of Management and Budget (the budgetary arm of the executive branch) from 2003 to 2006 and as White House chief of staff during the last three years of the Bush administration, taught a six-week graduate course, “Averting the U.S. Fiscal Crisis,” this semester in the Woodrow Wilson School. (Bolten taught a companion course for undergraduates last fall.) Fifteen students studied the budget — how it is developed, what goes into it, and how the gaping fiscal imbalance might be fixed. At the second class meeting, Bolten laid out the bad news in a series of PowerPoint slides.  

According to the CBO, he showed, the federal government last year took in $2.15 trillion but spent $3.46 trillion, leaving a deficit of $1.31 trillion. In the current fiscal year, the deficit is expected to go even higher, to about $1.5 trillion, and under the Obama administration’s proposed budget for the 2012 fiscal year, which Congress already has begun debating, the deficit would be $1.65 ­trillion.  

Numbers that large are difficult to imagine, but a trillion one-dollar bills stacked on top of each other would reach more than a quarter of the way to the moon. A more informative way to look at the deficit, though, is as a percentage of the country’s gross domestic product. Bolten’s slides show that over the last half-century, the annual deficit has averaged about 2.5 percent of GDP. Even during the 1980s and early 1990s, when many were calling for a constitutional amendment to eliminate Reagan-era deficits, it never got above 6 percent.  

But last year’s deficit was 8.9 percent of GDP, down slightly from 2009’s 10 percent, which was the highest it’s been since the Cold War. Under the CBO’s worst-case scenario it could rise to more than 32 percent by 2035. The national debt — the cumulative total of all the deficits we have run over the years, offset by any surpluses — jumped from 36 percent of GDP as recently as 2007 to 62 percent last year and could, the CBO projects, go as high as 185 percent by 2035. Even if it remains in its current range, most analysts agree that such a level of debt is not sustainable.  

Some economists dismiss the notion that the deficit requires massive budget-cutting immediately and at any cost. Princeton professor Paul Krugman, winner of the Nobel Prize in economics, wrote in The New York Times on March 10: “The nation is not, in fact, ‘broke.’ The federal government is having no trouble raising money ... So there’s no need to scramble to slash spending now now now; we can and should be willing to spend now if it will produce savings in the long run.” Krugman argues that the nation’s long-term deficit problem is driven mainly by health-care costs, so policymakers “should be looking for ways to rein in health spending over the long term” — by spending on things like prevention and research.

Peter Orszag '91

Bloomberg via Getty Images - Andrew Harrer

Peter Orszag '91

“The deficit we have right now is not a massive national threat, but the deficit that is projected for the future is a massive national threat if we don’t deal with it,” says Peter Orszag ’91, who served as CBO director from 2007 to 2008 and as OMB director in 2009 and 2010. “The challenge that we have is that we don’t tend to deal very well with problems before they become crises. We are on an unsustainable path, and it’s not clear how we get off of it without suffering severe injury.”

What might that “severe injury” be? The CBO helpfully laid out such a doomsday scenario last summer in a policy paper, “Federal Debt and the Risk of a Fiscal Crisis” (available online at www.cbo.gov). Currently, when the country runs out of money, it simply borrows more by selling government debt (Treasury bills) to private and ­institutional investors. Much of it is bought by foreign governments, especially China, which is now the largest single foreign holder of U.S. government debt.  

If the financial markets concluded that our debt had grown beyond our ability to repay it, investors might stop buying it. The government would have no choice but to raise interest rates to whatever level was needed to lure those investors back. If interest rates on Treasury bills were to rise by even 4 percentage points, the CBO estimates, federal interest payments would increase by 40 percent — which would only make the deficit even bigger and accelerate what Orszag calls a “vicious feedback loop.” An increase in interest rates also would reduce the value of government bonds that already have been sold, which might force some of the mutual funds, pension funds, banks, and insurance companies that hold them into bankruptcy.

Alternatives would be, as the CBO puts it, “limited and unattractive.” They include rampant inflation, if the country chose to print still more money; large, overnight tax hikes, which could shove the economy into another deep recession; or deep and immediate cuts — perhaps 25 percent or more — in Social Security and Medicare. With the government’s credit cards maxed out, so to speak, there also would be no way to spend additional money in response to an unexpected national emergency.

At what point would things collapse, and how much time do we have? “That,” Bolten jokes in an interview, “may be the $64 trillion question.”    

Gregory Mankiw '80

Brian Smith

Gregory Mankiw '80

“A lot of it is a function of market psychology,” says Gregory Mankiw ’80, a Harvard economist who chaired the Council of Economic Advisers from 2003 to 2005. “In general, the bond market has tended to give the U.S. the benefit of the doubt.” That is to say, investors keep buying our debt because we have the biggest economy, the dollar remains the world’s reserve currency, and we are perceived as a safe, politically stable place for their money.  

Panics, however, tend to happen during economic downturns, and when they happen, they often arrive suddenly but with sickening speed. The CBO suggests that the United States is not facing a Greek-style collapse — yet. But the longer we wait to address the deficit, the greater the risk — and the less room for maneuvering if a crisis comes.

Orszag agrees that it would be a grave mistake to cross our fingers and hope for the best. “People assume that we’re the United States, it can never happen to us,” he says of a fiscal collapse, “but we have never on a sustained basis run excessive budget deficits over an extended period of time, outside of a war.”  

One crucial decision would have to be made this spring. Federal law limits how much the government can borrow, and we were expected to reach that “debt ceiling” as early as March 31. But there have been rumblings — particularly within the Tea Party — about not doing that this time. Economists feared that a refusal to raise the ceiling, or even a credible threat to do so, could be the event that saps lenders’ confidence that they eventually will get their money back.

“We don’t have any recent experience in this country at defaulting on the federal debt,” Elmendorf says. “And I don’t know any analysts who think we should experiment and see what happens.”

There are, economists explain, two parts of the deficit problem. Much of our current deficit is attributable to the 2008–09 financial meltdown (the 2007 deficit was just $161 billion, a little more than a tenth of what it is now). Tax revenues fell, automatic stabilizers such as unemployment insurance kicked in, and the government administered a strong dose of Keynesian stimulus to jolt the economy out of recession. As the economy improves and tax revenues pick up again over the next few years, the deficit is expected to shrink, although the budget would be nowhere near balanced. But over the next 20 years or so, the deficit will begin rising again — and this will be a much harder problem to address, because it is structural. Most of that gap will be caused by rapidly rising expenditures on health care, particularly Social Security and Medicare, as the baby boomers grow old.  

Last December, the Obama administration reached a deal with congressional Republicans to extend the Bush tax cuts for two years in exchange for measures designed to stimulate the economy and create jobs. In the short term, that added almost another trillion dollars to the deficit. That might seem to be exactly the wrong move, but Elmendorf is among the economists who say a short-term stimulus when the economy remains weak is not inconsistent with long-term fiscal restraint, even if it is paid for with more borrowed money. The problem is that the borrowing occurs now, and the belt-tightening is put off again for another day.

There are two main ways to reduce any deficit: Cut spending or raise revenues. Conservatives tend to favor the former; liberals, the latter. Any solution almost certainly will have to include both. Simply allowing the Bush tax cuts to expire in 2012 would cut the projected deficit by $600 billion. But doing so now could stall the economic recovery and would face strong Republican opposition. Although many have focused on cutting discretionary spending — that part of the budget that funds everything except defense, Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid, interest on the debt, and other mandatory payments — such spending accounts for only about 17 percent of the budget. Another suggestion, eliminating congressional earmarks, accounts for less than 2 percent of federal expenditures. Both Congress and the administration are learning just how hard the choices really are.  

Orszag says that the health-care reform legislation enacted last year will curb the growth in health-care expenditures and reduce the long-term deficit — assuming it is funded and implemented. There also have been at least a dozen ­serious proposals to reduce the deficit going forward, and Bolten’s class was to examine each of them and assess their strengths and shortcomings. Bolten admits to being partial to a plan by Wisconsin Rep. Paul Ryan, the new chairman of the House Budget Committee, whom Mankiw, another fan, praises as “the most serious person on the Republican side.” Ryan would make vast changes in the way government ­operates, privatizing part of Social Security and Medicare; providing a refundable tax credit to pay for health insurance; eliminating the estate, corporate income, and alternative minimum taxes; and placing a binding ceiling on total government spending.

Last December, the National Commission on Fiscal Responsibility and Reform, chaired by former Republican Sen. Alan Simpson and former White House Chief of Staff Erskine Bowles, a Democrat, issued a long draft report that advocated, among other things, cutting defense spending, increasing the gasoline tax, raising the retirement age for Social Security, and limiting Social Security and Medicare benefits for the wealthy. Mankiw has written favorably about some proposals to raise revenue by broadening the tax base, eliminating such sacred cows as the deductions for mortgage interest and state and local tax payments, and taxing ­employer-provided health-care benefits. (Though it drew some bipartisan praise, the commission’s draft report drew criticism and could not command enough support from its own members to be issued officially.)  

Around the same time the Simpson-Bowles draft came out, the CBO issued another paper, “The Economic Impacts of Waiting to Address the Budget Imbalance,” in which it pointed out that straightening our fiscal house in 2015 would require tax hikes or revenue cuts equal to about 2 to 2.5   percent of GDP. Wait another 10 years until 2025, though, and we will have to raise or cut about 8 to 9 percent of GDP. “Ultimately the fiscal imbalance will have to be addressed,” the report concludes, “whether quickly or gradually, and the longer the necessary adjustments are delayed, the more drastic they will need to be.”

“Our political system has never dealt well with gradual long-term problems,” Orszag observes. “It deals with crises. You can’t credibly go to a member of Congress today and say, ‘If you don’t fix this problem now, the bond market’s going to collapse tomorrow.’ You can continue to [use that rationale] tomorrow, and the day after that, and the day after that, and the day after that.” Until the day finally arrives when it does collapse.  

Mankiw, for his part, cites with hope Winston Churchill’s observation that Americans will always do the right thing — after they have exhausted all the alternatives.  

Mark F. Bernstein ’83 is PAW’s senior writer.

5 Responses

Donald H. Voss ’44

8 Years Ago

Caveat on fiscal policy

[node:field-image-collection:0:render]

Then there is the economy: Economic activity is subject to fluctuations. Most economists believe that the federal government has a legitimate role in countering recessions. The rationale for countercyclical compensatory fiscal policy is that the government will engage in deficit spending (financed by monetization of public debt) to stimulate sagging activity, and then repay the debt when prosperity returns. For this to work properly, both the spending and the repayment must occur. Unhappily, our government has shown disdain for the second element of the protocol.

During World War II (fall semester 1942, if I recall correctly), Professor Edwin Kemmerer — well known in his day as “The Money Doctor” for his work in stabilizing the finances of several governments, in part by converting their currencies to the gold or gold-exchange standard — returned to the campus to replace faculty departed for national service.

In a “Money and Banking” precept, a student asked Professor Kemmerer what he thought about fiat money systems (those not linked to gold or silver). The answer amazed us: A fiat currency could be the basis for a satisfactory monetary system! He added that this would require responsible behavior on the part of government. The wisdom of that caveat is demonstrated by the recent level of federal deficits and a public debt of $14 ­trillion.

Den Bergh ’50

8 Years Ago

Gold-plated education

PAW’s April 6 cover story, “Deficit disorder,” helps in understanding why the University of Texas has just added $500 million in gold to its endowment, bringing its total bullion holdings to $987 million. Sixty-three years ago my Princeton tuition, room, and board cost me the equivalent of 57 ounces of gold per year, an expenditure that would have set me back only 35 ounces of gold in 2010. Clearly, automation and harder-working professors are making education cheaper.

If this trend continues, it will take only about 25 Canadian gold Maple Leaf coins per year to pay for my granddaughter’s (Class of 2020, I hope) education.

Laurence C. Day ’55

8 Years Ago

Let economists teach economics

Why does Princeton engage alumni who were in government service with the CBO and OMB to teach students (cover story, April 6) when we have academic professors in the economics department hired for that job and responsibility? It appears we are a tributary backwater for former government officials, many with Republican ideological conservative economic principles, to wear an academic hat. First it was former Sen. Bill Frist ’74; now it is former OMB director Josh Bolten ’76. As a few-times visiting lecturer, they may pass the test; but a permanent seat at our table, I think not. Is this the payoff for enticing large Aspire campaign gifts? We have a superb group of professors/economists in our economics department. Teaching does not have to be diluted by those who happened to hold office via political appointments. 

This article is just more hand-wringing by deficit hawks, none of whom ever experienced personally the full brunt of the Great Depression. That Bolten and Gregory Mankiw '80 even give Rep. Paul Ryan’s plans the time of day is astounding. These two baby boomers with privileged paths and smooth hands never have lived on the street through economic turmoil until now. If they want to reduce the deficit, look to the banks and financial institutions that were responsible for the fiscal crisis to reign in their casino roulette wheels, derivatives trading desks, and unjustifiable compensation for symbolic starters. They caused this deficit; let them be taxed to the utmost for their irresponsibility. 

It is an equally sad commentary that a large percentage of graduates opt for careers in finance. Maybe we should look to Solomon Brothers alumnus author Michael Lewis ’82 to do a stint at the Wilson School to convey some outlandish truths about banking and finance in the real world. We might ask former Fed chairman Paul Volcker ’49 to introduce him. 

Peter Orszag ’91 says we have never run excessive budget deficits over an extended period of time, “outside of a war.” Has he looked east out of his window lately, or do the lost lives and defense expenditures in the Mideast only fall in the accountant's column as off-balance-sheet police action? But he might look beyond his limited definition of war to view the vastly understated unemployment numbers as the looming war against myopic deficit hawks who see government run by corporate America for corporate America.

The government underfunded TARP by half, as economist Paul Krugman has pointed out time and again to the deaf ears and blind eyes of some Princeton plutocrats. If we are to reassert the values and heightened principles of an equal democracy for all, serious large government spending programs suchas FDR pushed in the depth of the Depression would lead to reduced unemployment, stimulate private sector employment as a spinoff, and – surprise, surprise – increase tax revenues. Keynes was a bellwether.  And for the inflation worrywarts, when it appears to be headed above the Fed’s target after recovery had been stimulated with determination, one of our own at the helm, Ben Bernanke, will head it off at the pass with a dose of stringent monetary policy. Economics is not rocket science. 

The long-term deficit problem then can be addressed by raising taxes dramatically on tax-avoidance corporations and our mega-rich oligarchs and by closing absurd loopholes, just for openers. Awash in trillions in cash, most public corporations will not feel any pain and suffering as they cry all the way to their fleet of yachts and Dubai beach houses. Let Princeton economists teach economics, and let’s have a PAW cover story striking a balance with their views of “America’s Looming Deficit,” rather than leave us hanging on the positions of alumni “experts,” a presumptuous word subject to loose interpretation.

R.E. Stratton ’60

8 Years Ago

PAW's deficit experts

After reading about elitist deficit hawks in your last issue (cover story, April 6), I was relieved that very little was said on two subjects: ending all military adventurism worldwide, and making the wealthy and their corporations pay their fair share of taxes; and I was happy that Paul Krugman’s ideas were given only one paragraph. After all, what’s a Nobel Prize worth?

Also, I was pleased to read of some of your experts’ approval of the Ryan plan for two reasons: It shows proper contempt for the poor (formerly quaintly called “the middle class”) and the old among us; and its math isn’t quite as fuzzy as many critics say. Not quite.

Still, I suppose that very few — almost none of us conceivably belonging to the “welfare class” — need concern ourselves with such socially unattractive matters. Now hold my mint julep, will you, while I bust another union and tell the lesser among us to tighten their belts. After all, they shouldn’t live forever.

Nina Bang-Jensen ’77

8 Years Ago

Women missing from deficit story

PAW regularly does a good job of presenting complex issues in limited space. Therefore, I was startled that “Mind the gap: Alumni experts on America’s looming deficit” neglected to include (or even mention) a single female “expert.”

That same issue included an article about the University’s discouraging report documenting declining participation among current female students in “high-profile” campus roles. Without straining too hard, I can think of female classmates and other alumnae who are senior professors of economics at some of the best colleges and universities in the country, who lead companies employing thousands, and who, as government officials, deal with the deficit debate daily.

On the eve of Princeton’s celebration of its women, could PAW’s unintentional omission of a large portion of its alumni experts be both a reflection of the problem on campus and a missed opportunity to contribute to its solution?

Join the conversation

Plain text

Full name and Princeton affiliation (if applicable) are required for all published comments. For more information, view our commenting policy. Responses are limited to 500 words for online and 250 words for print consideration.

Related News

Newsletters.
Get More From PAW In Your Inbox.

Learn More

Title complimentary graphics